- land reform
-
any program, esp. when undertaken by a national government, involving the redistribution of agricultural land among the landless.[1840-50, Amer.]
* * *
Deliberate change in the way agricultural land is held or owned, the methods of its cultivation, or the relation of agriculture to the rest of the economy.The most common political objective of land reform is to abolish feudal or colonial forms of landownership, often by taking land away from large landowners and redistributing it to landless peasants. Other goals include improving the social status of peasants and coordinating agricultural production with industrialization programs. The earliest record of land reform is from 6th-century-BC Athens, where Solon abolished the debt system that forced peasants to mortgage their land and labour. The concentration of land in the hands of large landowners became the rule in the ancient world, however, and remained so through the Middle Ages and the Renaissance. The French Revolution brought land reform to France and established the small family farm as the cornerstone of French democracy. Serfdom was abolished throughout most of Europe in the 19th century. The Russian serfs were emancipated in 1861, and the Russian Revolution of 1917 introduced collectivization of agriculture, attended by loss of capital and devastating famines. Land reform was instituted in a number of other countries where communists came to power, notably China. It remains a potent political issue in many parts of the world. See also absentee ownership.* * *
Introductiona purposive change in the way in which agricultural land is held or owned, the methods of cultivation that are employed, or the relation of agriculture to the rest of the economy. Reforms such as these may be proclaimed by a government, by interested groups, or by revolution.The concept of land reform has varied over time according to the range of functions which land itself has performed: as a factor of production, a store of value and wealth, a status symbol, or a source of social and political influence. Land value reflects its relative scarcity, which in a market economy usually depends on the ratio between the area of usable land and the size of that area's population. As the per capita land area declines, the relative value of land rises, and land becomes increasingly a source of conflict among economic and social groups within the community.The patterns of wealth and income distribution and of social and political influence are partly determined by the laws governing land tenure. These laws specify the acceptable forms of tenure and the privileges and responsibilities that go with them. They define the land title and the extent to which the owner can freely dispose of it and of the income accruing from its use. In this sense, the form of tenure determines the wealth and income distribution based on the land: if private ownership is permitted, class differentiation is unavoidable; in contrast, public ownership eliminates such distinctions. The forms of tenure range from temporary, conditional holding to ownership in fee simple, which confers total unencumbered rights of control and disposal over the land.Historically, land reform meant reform of the tenure system or redistribution of the land ownership rights. In recent decades the concept has been broadened in recognition of the strategic role of land and agriculture (agriculture, origins of) in development. Land reform has therefore become synonymous with agrarian reform or a rapid improvement of the agrarian structure, which comprises the land tenure system, the pattern of cultivation and farm organization, the scale of farm operation, the terms of tenancy, and the institutions of rural credit, marketing, and education. It also deals with the state of technology, or with any combination of these factors, as shown by modern reform movements, regardless of the political or ideological orientation of the reformers.Objectives of reformReform is usually introduced by government initiative or in response to internal and external pressures, to resolve or prevent an economic, social, or political crisis. Thus reform may be considered a problem-solving mechanism. The true motives for reform, however, may well differ from those announced by the reformer. The distinction between the real and proclaimed objectives may be especially significant if the proclaimed objectives have been forced upon reformers who do not support those objectives. The reformers may proclaim certain objectives merely to appease the peasants, to undermine opposition, to win international backing, or to safeguard their own positions. The proclaimed purposes of land reform, however, will be the point of departure in this article.Political and social objectivesThe most common proclaimed objective of land reform is to abolish feudalism, which usually means overthrowing the landlord class and transferring its powers to the reforming elite or its surrogates. If “foreigners” happen to be among the landlord class, the objectives become the defeat of imperialism and the end of foreign exploitation.Another common objective is to free the peasants (peasant) from subjugation to and dependence on the exploiters and make them active citizens by restoring what assertedly had been taken away from them.A third objective is to create democracy—a stated purpose of both capitalist and Communist reformers. Most capitalist reforms are based on the premise that individual private ownership (capitalism) in the form of independent family farms will promote and sustain democratic institutions.Communist (communism) reformers, in contrast, usually aim at overthrowing both feudalism and capitalism on the premise that, as a means of production, private ownership of land inherently breeds exploitation. In practice, this means “returning land to the tillers” and creating a classless, democratic society. A more immediate and practical goal of Communist reformers has often been to rally the peasants in support of the new order and against the former regime.Finally, reform may be introduced simply as the most expedient way to resolve a crisis or avoid a revolution. The reformer, in this case, will introduce and implement just enough reform to appease the peasants and contain the conflict. This happens especially when the reformers are still in sympathy with the landlord class and consciously prefer a moderate rather than a radical reform.These political objectives tend to undergo change during the period of implementation and are, therefore, kept vague enough to permit flexibility and modification as conditions change.All land reforms emphasize the need to improve the peasants' social (social change) conditions and status, to alleviate poverty, and to redistribute income and wealth in their favour. They try to create employment opportunities and education and health services and to redistribute the benefits to the community at large, the younger generation as the main target.Economic objectiveseconomic development has become a major objective of governments and political parties in recent decades. Efforts have been made to encourage agricultural (agricultural economics) progress by means of agrarian reform in favour of the peasant who does not own his land or whose share of the crop is relatively small, and who therefore has little incentive to invest capital or expend effort to improve the land and raise productivity. Another mechanism has been to encourage labour-intensive cultivation, on the assumption that traditional or feudal landowners often use their land extensively and wastefully.An equally important economic objective is to promote optimum-scale farming operations. Excessively large farms (latifundia) and excessively small farms (minifundia) tend to be inefficient. Therefore, reform aims at creating farms of optimum size given the land quality, the crop, and the level of technology.Finally, reform aims at coordinating agriculture with the rest of the economy. In their quest for economic development and industrialization, reformers attempt to make the rural sector more responsive to the needs of the industrial sector for labour, food, industrial raw materials, capital, and foreign currency. These functions are often expected to be performed simultaneously.Types of reformWhether it is called land reform or agrarian reform, the operational concept covers five main types of reform, classified according to whether they deal with land title and terms of holding, land distribution, the scale of operation, the pattern of cultivation, or supplementary measures such as credit, marketing, or extension services.Reforms concerned with the title to land and the terms of holding reflect a transition from tradition-bound to formal and contractual systems of landholding (property law). Their implementation involves property surveys, recording of titles, and provisions to free the landholder from restrictions or obligations imposed by tradition. Property surveys are conducted wherever land is held by a tribe or clan or where reallocation of cultivable land routinely follows tradition. In these situations the landholder may lack the incentive to improve the land because the right of disposal belongs to the tribe, clan, or feudal lord, as in medieval Europe and in parts of present-day Africa and the South Pacific islands. Such reform affects landholding in at least three ways: it may increase security of tenure and hence incentives; it may reorganize the system of inheritance in favour of offspring; and it may bring land onto the market so that land transactions become possible. This reform, however, has little immediate effect on the scale of operation, but it does facilitate future land concentration and fragmentation. In countries where the terms of holding and tenancy are regulated by tradition, reform may seek to convert tenancy into a contractual agreement that offers some protection to the tenant and more security and incentive to improve the land and advance technology, as in Japan, India, and Pakistan.The most common type of reform involves the redistribution of land titles from one individual to another, from individuals to a group or community at large, or from a group to individuals. The land of one landlord may be redistributed to many individuals, as in Egypt, Iran, or Ireland. Or the land of individuals may be reallocated in favour of the community at large by abolishing private ownership, as in Cuba and China. Or, again, public land may be distributed to individuals, as in various parts of Latin America.The impact of redistribution on the scale of operations and on marketability of the land depends on the form it takes and the restrictions attached to it. If the redistributed farm was previously operated as a unit, its division means fragmentation and reduction of scale; however, if it was operated in fragments by tenants, transfer of title to the tenants would not affect the scale. The final results depend on the measures taken to prevent adverse effects.Land-tenure reform, of course, can improve the scale of operations by enlarging the farm or by reducing it. Enlargement applies when the holding is increased in size, either by adding to it or by consolidating its fragmented parts. Farm consolidation involves reallocation of the total farmland within a region by land exchange, sale, or lease such that no one loses and all gain by increasing efficiency. The scale of operations may be increased by pooling resources, as in farm cooperatives (cooperative) and collectives that offer facilities otherwise inaccessible to a small farm.An equally common approach is to divide large, extensively cultivated farms into smaller and more intensively cultivable units. Reduction of the scale, however, has potential problems since it may result in excessively small units or in the breakup of efficiently run farms. Operations below the optimum level may inhibit improvements in technology, capital investment, and diversification.Changes in the pattern of cultivation relate directly to cultivation, land yield, and labour productivity. While other types of reform may influence productivity indirectly by enhancing security of tenure and the scale of operation, improvements in the pattern of cultivation affect productivity directly, through advances in technology, improved irrigation, and the application of chemicals.Technological advance usually implies mechanization, although it may be biological and organizational only, as in crop rotation, reconditioning of the soil, improved seeding, or better utilization of available technology. The state of technology determines the level of productivity or the ratio between outputs and inputs. More advanced technology permits the cultivation of more land per unit of labour, deeper plowing, better timing of farm operations, reclamation of areas previously inaccessible, and possibly wider diversification of the crops than previously attainable. By easing the physical burden of farm work, it helps to conserve human energy. Improved technology may also be the most direct way to modify tradition without an open confrontation or a political revolution. Mechanization and advanced technology may, of course, cause displacement of labour, unemployment, or the absorption of capital at the expense of other sectors, at least in the short run; in the long run, the positive effects tend to prevail.Improvements in irrigation (irrigation and drainage) include increasing the water supply, draining swampy land, and regulating the quantity and quality of water flow. Irrigation is especially important in that it involves large investments and infringes on tenure rights, both matters that invite public responsibility and intervention. Irrigation and technology are closely related to the use of fertilizer and other chemicals. Chemicals may be difficult to apply without irrigation, and neither may be practical unless farming technology has advanced beyond relatively primitive methods. Improvement of the pattern of cultivation may be inhibited, however, by traditional attitudes, the lack of skills, or the scarcity of capital. Another difficulty is that changes in the pattern of cultivation are usually long-term investments that may be too slow to satisfy immediate pressures for reform.Many improvements and changes may have to be implemented in areas outside the immediate sphere of agriculture, such as credit, marketing, and education. Unless the farmer is able and ready to take advantage of new opportunities and his product can be marketed profitably, reform efforts may be futile. Costly or inaccessible credit and the excessive charges of middlemen increase the relative costs of farming. Therefore, supervised credit, subsidies, and low-interest loans that help to replace traditional sources of credit have been common, and credit and marketing cooperatives and market regulation have been used to protect farmers against exploitation by middlemen.Finally, improvements in general education are essential in any reform that involves the modernization of agriculture. Extension services, literacy promotion programs, the teaching of home economics, and vocational training are of special importance in helping the young and unemployed and in providing skilled labour for industry.Evaluation and criteria of successAgrarian reform is a complex process of directed change, and its effects touch society in many ways. Therefore its evaluation may be difficult because the various social, political, and economic objectives may be inconsistent with each other. Even champions of reform and planners may have different ideas about it. Moreover, there are no generally accepted criteria for determining the success of such a program, nor adequate tools for measuring its progress.Economic criteriaEconomic indicators and criteria are basically the requisites of economic development. Economic development may be defined as a sustained increase in and achievement of a given level of per capita real income. To be sustained, the rise of per capita real income must be accompanied by changes in the economic and social structures of society, increase in total investment (capital formation), higher productivity, and full employment.Capital formation in agriculture implies that more resources will be put at the disposal of the farmer in the form of machinery, fertilizers, and irrigation and drainage facilities, all of which contribute to the productive capacity and productivity of the land and the worker. Because capital formation partly depends on domestic saving, a higher rate of capital formation may thus be an indicator of the success of the reform in aiding economic development.Another indicator is change in land yield or labour productivity. A rise in yield or productivity implies higher efficiency, better use of resources, and an advance in the state of technology. It also suggests an increase in the level of income and potential saving and investment. In fact, the increase in productivity may be the most important single indicator of the contribution made by reform to economic development. Change in the level of rural employment or unemployment provides another indicator, which should be reflected in the level and distribution of income.Finally, an important indicator may be the change in agriculture's responsiveness to the demands of industry and manufacturing. The ability of agriculture to provide labour, food, industrial raw materials, and a market for industrial products is a significant measure of its contribution to industrialization and development.Social criteriaSocial and political accomplishments are more difficult to measure. One of the important indicators may be the degree of peasant participation in activities such as voting, representation, and decision making. Social and political stability, or the tendency to change governments by constitutional and nonviolent means and continuity of the social and political order without resort to force, are other indicators.But these various indicators can only suggest that change has taken place. The results depend on the magnitude and relevance of the change. Assuming that measurement is feasible, three approaches to evaluation may be followed: the goal achievement approach, the perceived achievement approach, and the closing-the-gap (integrative) approach.Goal achievement considers a program successful to the extent that it realizes the goals specified prior to the reform. Probably the most common economic goal is maximization, according to which efficiency dictates that reform should continue up to the point where the marginal benefit of reform is equal to its marginal cost. Land distribution in this case will continue up to the point where its net benefit is zero. Another common goal is to realize incremental gains as the reform proceeds. The reform would be successful to the extent that the effects have been positive. A 20-percent increase in capital formation in a capital-poor economy, however, may be more significant than a 20-percent increase in a capital-rich economy. Similarly, a 20-percent decline in the number of dissatisfied peasants in a peaceful or democratic society may be more conducive to stability and harmony than a 20-percent decline in a radical or violent society. Hence, this approach requires that a critical minimum achievement be specified as a criterion of success in each situation. Or, as a third alternative, the evaluation may compare the results with targets proclaimed in advance. The degree of success will be the extent to which those targets have been realized. Problems, however, will arise, especially when the goals happen to be contradictory or change over time.Perceived achievement considers reform successful if the relevant parties perceive their goals as having been satisfied. One of the main objectives of reform has been to reduce conflict and promote harmony, both of which depend on whether a person or group perceives its expectations as fulfilled, whether it has hope that these expectations will be fulfilled, and whether it is able to express these expectations openly. The evaluation, therefore, is primarily subjective, and the net impact can be assessed only by synthesizing the views of the parties affected, including those who might be satisfied to have their losses minimized, just as much as others would want their gains maximized.The closing-the-gap approach considers a reform successful to the extent that it closes the gap between the sector subject to reform and the more advanced sectors in society; in other words, reform would be expected to help integrate agriculture with the rest of the economy and the rural population with the urban community in terms of opportunities and levels of living. In this sense the reform would remove the dualism between the agrarian and the nonagrarian, between the technologically backward and the technologically advanced, and thus would increase labour mobility in response to the demands of the economy and development.History of land reformThe ideas and principles discussed so far may be illustrated by a selective survey of the history of land reform.Ancient reformsThe recorded history of reform begins with the Greeks (ancient Greek civilization) and Romans of the 6th and 2nd centuries BC, respectively. Land in ancient Athens was held in perpetuity by the tribe or clan, with individual holdings periodically reallocated according to family size and soil fertility. Population increase, expansion of trade, growth of a money economy, and the opening up of business opportunities eventually made financial transactions in land an economic necessity. Land itself continued to be inalienable, but the right to use the land could be mortgaged (mortgage). Thus, peasants could secure loans by surrendering their rights to the product of the land, as “sale with the option of redemption.” Lacking other employment, the debtor continued to cultivate the land as hektēmor, or sixth partner, delivering five-sixths of the product to the creditor and retaining the rest for himself. Mortgaged land was marked by horoi, or mortgage stones, which served as symbols of land enserfment. When Solon was elected archon, or chief magistrate, c. 594 BC, his main objective was to free the land and destroy the horoi. His reform law, known as the seisachtheia, or “shaking-off the burdens,” cancelled all debts, freed the hektēmoroi, destroyed the horoi, and restored land to its constitutional holders. Solon also prohibited the mortgaging of land or of personal freedom on account of debt.The impact of the reform was extensive but of short duration. The hektēmoroi were freed, but since no alternative sources of support or credit were provided and creditors were uncompensated, dissatisfaction and instability persisted. Two decades of anarchy were followed by a revolution, c. 561 BC, that brought Peisistratus to power. He enforced the reform and distributed lands of his adversaries (who were killed or exiled) among the small holders. He also extended loans to aid cultivation and prevent migration to the city and expanded silver mining to create employment. Although the amount of land redistributed is unknown, Peisistratus was apparently able to satisfy the peasantry, secure their loyalty, and stay in power for life, but the economic effects are too vague to evaluate.The Roman (ancient Rome) reform by Tiberius (Gracchus, Tiberius Sempronius) and Gaius Gracchus (Gracchus, Gaius Sempronius) came between 133 and 121 BC. The land reform law, or lex agraria, of Tiberius was passed by popular support against serious resistance by the nobility. It applied only to former public land, ager publicus, which had been usurped and concentrated in the hands of large landholders. Land concentration reduced the number of owners and hence the number of citizens and those eligible to serve in the army. In addition, such concentration was accompanied by a shift from cultivation to grazing, which reduced employment and increased the poverty of the peasants, producing a crisis. The motives of the reformers continue to be debated, but it would appear that concern for the poor and political stability were major factors.The lex agraria specified minimum and maximum individual landholdings, with an allowance for male children of the family. Excess land would be expropriated and compensation paid for improvements. A standing collegium, or commission, was to enforce the law, but implementation was delayed because Tiberius was killed in the year of its passage. When Gaius was elected tribune about a decade later, he revived the reform and went even further. He colonized new land and abolished rent on small holdings since rent on large holdings had been suspended as compensation for expropriation. Gaius was killed in 121 BC, however, and within a decade the reform was reversed: private acquisition of public land was legalized, the land commission was dissolved, rent on public land was abolished, all holdings were declared private property, and squatting on public land was prohibited. Even colonization was ended, and colonies established by Gaius were broken up. Another period of land concentration was inaugurated.Modern European reformsThe French Revolution brought a new era in the history of land reform. Reform meant dealing with survivals of the medieval (Middle Ages) tenures that had left a common heritage in most European countries (France) and, through them, in the colonies. The measures and approaches varied from place to place and period to period.On the eve of the Revolution, French society was polarized, with the nobility and clergy on one side and the rising business class on the other. The middle class was relatively small, especially in the rural areas. The majority of the peasants were hereditary tenants, either censiers, who paid a fixed money rent, or mainmortables, or serfs (serfdom), who paid rent in the form of labour services, corvée, of about three days a week. The peasants paid various other feudal (feudal land tenure) dues and taxes, from which the nobility and clergy were exempted. The Revolution overthrew the ancien régime and the feudal order and introduced land reform.The reform repealed feudal tenures, freed all persons from serfdom, abolished feudal courts, and cancelled all payments not based on real property, including tithes. Rents based on real property were redeemable. Once the law had been passed, however, the peasants seized the land and refused to pay any rents or redemption fees; in 1792 all payments were finally cancelled. Land of the clergy and political emigrants was confiscated and sold at auction, together with common land. The terms of sale, however, often favoured the wealthy, which may explain the rise of a new class of large landowners among the supporters of Napoleon.The social and political objectives of the reformers were fully realized. The censiers and serfs became owners. Feudalism was destroyed, and the new regime won peasant support. The economic effects, however, were limited. Incentives could not be increased substantially since the peasants already had full security of tenure prior to the reform. The scale of operations was not changed; and no facilities for credit, marketing, or capital formation were created. The major achievements were the reinforcement of private, individual ownership and perpetuation of the small family farm as a basis of democracy. The small family farm has characterized French agriculture ever since.There were other reforms in most European countries. England (United Kingdom) resolved its land problems by the enclosure movement, which drove the small peasants into the towns, consolidated landholdings, and promoted large-scale operation and private ownership. Sweden and Denmark pioneered between 1827 and 1830 by peacefully abolishing village compulsion, or imposed labour service, and the strip system of cultivation, by consolidating the land, and by dividing the commons among the peasants. Though influenced by the French Revolution, only after the 1848 revolutions did Germany, Italy, and Spain free the peasants and redistribute the land. Reform in Ireland took a whole century before substantive results were achieved, in the mid-1930s, after Ireland was divided into Northern Ireland and the Irish Free State. The tenants were converted into owners by subsidized purchase of the land.The first major Russian (Russia) reform was the emancipation (Emancipation Manifesto) of the serfs in 1861. At the time of emancipation about 45 percent of the land was private property and the remainder was held as allotment land, cultivated in units averaging 9.5 acres (3.8 hectares) by the peasant serfs against rent in kind and labour, payable to feudal lords. In contrast, fewer than 1,000 noble families owned about 175,000,000 acres (70,000,000 hectares) and received rent therefrom. Conflict between such extremes of poverty and wealth caused restlessness among the peasants and rendered reform inevitable. As Tsar Alexander II put it: “It is better to abolish serfdom from above than to await the day when it will begin to abolish itself from below.”The Emancipation Act of 1861 abolished serfdom and distributed allotment land among the peasants. The homestead became hereditary property of the individual, but the field land was vested in the village mir as a whole. The peasant paid redemption through the village authority, while the landlord received state bonds as compensation equal to 75 to 80 percent of the land market value. Though legally freed, the private serf had to ransom his freedom by surrendering a part of the allotment land. In contrast, serfs belonging to the imperial family were emancipated in 1863 and received the maximum amount of land fixed by law. Serfs of the state were emancipated in 1866 and allowed to keep the land they occupied against money rent. The Cossacks received two-thirds of the land, to be held in common, but in lieu of redemption payments they had to serve 20 years in the army. The serfs in mines and households were freed but received no economic assets.Redemption payments, however, soon proved too burdensome, village restrictions were tight, and the allotment land area declined, all of which led to renewed restlessness and disturbances. Following the revolt of 1905, the government, under Pyotr Stolypin (Stolypin, Pyotr Arkadyevich), tried to create middle-class, independent farmers by replacing the village tenure with private ownership, consolidating holdings, and encouraging land purchase by individuals; but the time was too short for effective implementation. The Soviet Revolution (Russian Revolution of 1905) overthrew the tsarist regime and introduced the concepts of public ownership and collectivization.By decree in 1918, the Soviets (Union of Soviet Socialist Republics) abolished private ownership of land, made farming the sole basis of landholding, and declared collectivization a major objective of policy. Marketing of agricultural products became a state monopoly. In 1929 Stalin (Stalin, Joseph) embarked on a full course of collectivization, and by 1938 collective farms occupied 85.6 percent of the land and state farms 9.1 percent. Credit facilities and tractor stations supplemented collectivization, while agricultural production was integrated in the national plan for industrialization and development.The costs of Soviet reform included the destruction of capital and the death of large numbers of kulaks, or rich peasants. Total output and productivity increased, however, and capital formation was made possible through forced saving, taxes, and regulated prices. The peasant received extensive social services such as health care, and education and better working conditions. The objectives of the decree of 1918 have been fully realized.Reform in eastern Europe was complicated by the fact that most of the eastern European countries remained under foreign rule until the middle of the 19th century or later. In Hungary, the Decree of 1853 abolished the robot, or forced labour and feudal dues, freed the serfs, liberalized land transaction, and encouraged consolidation. The Romanian (Romania) reform of 1864 freed the serfs and distributed both the land and the redemption payments in proportion to the number of cows or oxen each peasant had. Formal emancipation in Bulgaria was introduced by the Turkish government in the 1850s, but actual reform came in 1880, after independence. Each peasant, including sharecroppers and wage workers, who had worked the land for 10 years without interruption, was entitled to the land he had cultivated. With the exception of Bulgaria, the distribution of ownership throughout most of eastern Europe remained highly uneven. Political instability reached a dangerous point between the two world wars. Following World War II, the eastern European countries established Communist governments with a strong tendency toward collective, cooperative, and mechanized agriculture.The Mexican reform of 1915 followed a revolution and dealt mainly with lands of Indian villages that had been illegally absorbed by neighbouring haciendas (hacienda) (plantations). Legally there was no serfdom; but the Indian wage workers, or peons (peonage), were reduced to virtual serfdom through indebtedness. Thus, the landlords were masters of the land and of the peons. The immediate aim of reform was to restore the land to its legal owners, settle the title, and use public land to reconstruct Indian villages. The motives were mainly to reduce poverty and inequality and to secure political stability, which was then in the balance. A decree of 1915 voided all land alienations that had taken place illegally since 1856 and provided for extracting land from haciendas to reestablish the collective Indian villages, or ejidos (ejido). The 1917 constitution reaffirmed those provisions but also guaranteed protection of private property, including haciendas. Nevertheless, a combination of loopholes, litigation, and reactionary forces slowed implementation, and effective reform came only after passage of the Agrarian Code of 1934 and the sympathetic efforts of Pres. Lázaro Cárdenas.The reform restored many villages and freed the peons, but land concentration and poverty continued. In 1950, more than 31 percent of the private cropland was owned by fewer than 0.5 percent of the owners. Small-scale operation was retained or encouraged, a fact explaining the decline of output in the early years. More recently, efficiently run farms have been exempted from distribution.The social and political impact was more positive. The peasants acquired more land and liberty, and control by landlords was reduced, although it was replaced by village restrictions. At least legally, farming became the basis of landholding. Some have seen in land reform the reason for Mexico's political stability, although there have been sporadic peasant uprisings and other violent encounters.Reforms since World War IIRecent decades have witnessed widespread, comprehensive reform programs, but the concept has undergone major changes. The eastern European countries and China originally followed the Soviet model, with different modifications in the individual countries. A few other countries have continued to follow that model, with major emphasis on “land to the tiller,” cooperation, collective ownership, large-scale operation, and mechanization, and with economic development as the common denominator. In capitalist-oriented reforms, private ownership, family farming, and dual tenures have remained basic objectives with the aim of promoting democracy, equality, stability, and development. Under the influence and with the guidance of the United Nations, nonsocialist reforms of the 1950s were equated with community development and emphasized institutional and rural self-help in addition to land redistribution. In the 1960s the emphasis shifted to agricultural productivity and economic development by means of large-scale operation, new technology, and cooperation. The 1970s witnessed the advent of “integrated rural development” as the focus of reform and as a way of combining productive activities with improvements in the social and physical infrastructure. The integrated approach, however, soon proved to be unmanageable, and the emphasis shifted to the “target” group as the focus of reform. The most recent conception of reform has been to satisfy “basic needs,” with or without land distribution, although no policymaker in the capitalist countries would openly question the idea of land redistribution or the creation of small family farms. These experiments with the concept of reform have been accompanied by attempts to broaden the concept to incorporate women as equal beneficiaries of reform in their own right. The results have been mixed.The Japanese reform came immediately after World War II at the insistence of the Allied Occupation Army. The reform was designed to fit the uniquely high literacy rate and advanced industrial level of the country. Although the Meiji (Meiji Restoration) government had formally abolished feudalism and declared the land to be the property of the peasants, usurpation of land by the rich and by moneylenders had created classes of perpetual tenants and absentee landlords. In 1943, 66 percent of the land was operated by tenants against rent in kind that averaged 48 percent of the farmers' product, while population pressure resulted in fragmentation of holdings. The social class structure was closely tied to tenure, the owners in each village being at the top of the structure. Conflict between landlords and peasants was widespread.After the war, the crisis was revived by food shortages, the breakdown of the urban economy, and the return of absentee landlords to the land. The Occupation Army insisted on reform, presumably to democratize the society and rehabilitate the economy. The reform law of 1946 established a ceiling on individual holdings and provided for expropriation and resale of excess land to the tenants against long-term payments. The government compensated the landlords in cash and bonds redeemable in 30 years. Tenants were protected by contract, and rents were reduced to a maximum of 25 percent of the product. The redistributed land was made inalienable, though this restriction was relaxed four years later. The program also provided for marketing and credit cooperatives. An important supplementary measure was the Local Autonomy Law of 1947, which decentralized the power structure and put village affairs in the hands of the villagers.Within two years tenancy declined by more than 80 percent. Rent control and land distribution helped to equalize incomes in the villages and rehabilitate the sociopolitical status of the peasants. Crop yields per unit of land increased, but despite improved techniques the output per worker declined. In general the reform seemed to realize the objectives of the reformers and the peasants, although smallness of scale, low per capita incomes, underemployment, and insufficient mechanization have persisted. Even black market rents developed. These problems were tolerable because their effects were mitigated by the upsurge of the urban economy and the ability of the Japanese farmer to supplement the family income from nonagricultural employment. Even so, the farmers continue to depend on government subsidy to stay in farming.EgyptThe Egyptian reform of 1952 followed the revolution that overthrew the monarchy and brought young middle-class leaders to the helm. Though affecting only about 12 percent of the arable land, it was applied thoroughly and touched all aspects of rural life. Egypt had two main forms of tenure: private ownership and waqf, or land held in trust and dedicated to charitable or educational purposes. Waqf land was inalienable, but private land was subject to speculation and concentration. In 1950, 1 percent of the owners had more than 20 percent of the private land, and 7 percent had more than two-thirds. The operating unit was small, with 77 percent of all the holdings occupying less than one acre each. Tenancy was widespread and rents were exorbitant. The peasants were exploited by middlemen who sublet the land to tenants, mediated between them and the market, and extended credit at high rates of interest.The revolutionary reformers aimed at abolishing feudalism, recruiting peasant support, promoting economic development, and bringing the villagers back into the stream of national life. The Agrarian Reform Law of 1952 put a ceiling on individual holdings at 200 faddāns (one faddān = 1.038 acres), later reduced to 100 faddāns, with special allowance for male children. The excess land was expropriated and distributed to the peasants in parcels not exceeding five faddāns. Compensation was given in bonds, while land recipients had to repay in annual installments. The new owners were obligated to join cooperatives for production, marketing, and credit. Tenancy conditions were also regulated, with contract replacing traditional terms; rent could not exceed 50 percent of the product, nor could a tenant hold more than 50 acres, to avoid subletting. An interesting feature of the reform was the special attention given to college graduates by allowing them up to 20-faddān parcels.The reform was enforced quickly and had a great impact on the morale of the peasants. The economic effects, however, were minor since agriculture was intensive and land yield high. Producer cooperatives served only to offset the impact of distribution on the scale of operation. Some increases in yield have been claimed, but the evidence is still inconclusive. Furthermore, little capital was redirected into productive investment since the compensation bonds were not negotiable. Peasant savings remained limited, income increments being spent mostly on consumption. Finally, underemployment in agriculture has remained widespread. The defects of the agrarian structure continue to prevail, and relatively large ownerships exist, while certain groups in Egypt are calling for reversal of the reform.The social and political effects, however, were far reaching. Redistribution and regulation of rent raised the incomes of small owners and tenants. Cooperatives replaced the middleman and captured his share for the farmer. The peasant gained social status and enjoyed a higher level of political participation, mostly in support of the revolutionary regime. These effects, however, can be easily exaggerated. The peasants became dependent on the cooperatives whether they liked them or not. Great differences in landholding continued to exist, and peasant incomes remained low. Black market rents appeared. The example of Egypt suggests that successful reform in densely populated countries requires an upsurge in the industrial sector to relieve population pressure and permit technical advance and higher productivity in agriculture.The model of Japan's reform has been attempted in Southeast Asia, especially in Taiwan, South Korea (Korea, South), and South Vietnam, all influenced by American experts and by the anti-Communism of the respective governments. The objectives were to sustain the political order, raise living standards, and promote some degree of economic development. The reforms began with regulation of tenancy, restriction of rent, and the institution of written contract for leases, following which tenants were to be transformed into owners. Taiwan's reform was implemented between 1949 and 1953, in three stages. First, rents, which had sometimes reached 70 percent of the product, were reduced to 37.5 percent. Next, tenant-farmed public land was sold to the tenants. Finally, tenant-farmed private land was bought by the government and resold to the tenants.The Vietnamese reform was introduced in 1955. Rents were reduced to a maximum of 25 percent of the product. A ceiling of 247 acres (100 hectares) was put on individual holdings, however, and only the excess land was subject to redistribution in parcels of 7.4 to 12.4 acres (three to five hectares) to the tenants. The collapse of the South Vietnamese regime and the unification of South and North Vietnam ended that reform and replaced it with the socialist model of North Vietnam.The reform in Taiwan, as in South Vietnam prior to unification, was supplemented by other measures described as community development, such as adult education, credit facilities, improved technology, and other social services. Though land consolidation was attempted, the scale of operation was little affected. The main effect seems to have been the regulation of tenancy and the redistribution of rent incomes. An innovation of Taiwan's reform was the partial compensation of landlords with industrial shares in public enterprises, which helped them and helped industry.Taiwan's reform has been hailed as a major success, in both economic and political terms. Some observers, however, are unwilling to reach such a conclusion until restrictions are removed and the peasants have a free choice of tenure and farm organization.South Korea's land reform (under the Land Reform Law of June 1949) roughly followed the Japanese model by removing tenancy, creating small ownerships, implementing the law thoroughly and promptly, and depending heavily on nonagricultural (basically industrial) employment to absorb labour and supplement rural income. Like the Japanese and Taiwanese reforms, Korea's successful reform was generously supported by foreign aid.The Philippines introduced a reform program in 1963, which aimed primarily at replacing share tenancy with lease contracts and eventually with ownership, and at revitalizing agriculture through extension services. By the mid-1980s the program had given titles to about 400,000 tenants and secure leases to another 600,000, but the economic viability of the new units has been uncertain because of their small scale and the lack of supplementary facilities. The main effects initially were seed improvement, greater use of fertilizers, and an increase in contractual tenancy. To combat the negative effects of small-scale farming, the Philippine government has resorted to what it calls the “compact farm,” which is a voluntary grouping of small farms to be operated under one management as one consolidated farm. The problem of surplus labour, however, remains to be solved.Various other reforms have been introduced in Southeast Asia, but the only innovative program has been that of Malaysia. The program in Malaysia has been highly organized and development oriented. It tries to promote social and economic objectives by emphasizing the production of rubber and palm oil for export and gradually transforming the landless into hereditary tenants on newly reclaimed and settled plantations. A typical plantation covers 4,500 to 5,000 acres (1,800 to 2,000 hectares) of jungle land and absorbs about 400 families. The land is cleared and planted by contract, and a village is constructed, with all the necessary services, before the settlers arrive. Each house has a quarter of an acre for a household garden. Cropland is divided in blocks of 120 to 200 acres (48 to 80 hectares), to be worked by a team of 15 to 25 people until the plants have matured. Upon maturation, each settler receives a share by lottery and a lease title for 99 years. This tenure arrangement precludes alienation, subdivision, or subleasing; it thus protects the tenant farmer and sidesteps the Islāmic laws of inheritance, which tend toward fragmentation of the land.The settler is responsible for the cost of clearing and planting, but the government pays the administrative costs. The settler is guaranteed supplementary employment to earn subsistence income pending maturity of the plants, and cultivation is guided by experts. The rate of settlement is determined by the overall economic plan. It is clear that landholding has become tied to cultivation; fragmentation and diseconomies of scale have been avoided, and cultivation has become a rational economic operation. The Malaysian program has much in common with the cooperative settlements of Israel and the Gezira Scheme in The Sudan.Latin America (Latin America, history of)Except for the early example of Mexico, reform in Latin America has been recent and appears to have come only in response to the threat of social and political instability and mounting international pressures. Reform in Latin America after World War II must be seen against a background of rapidly increasing population and of extreme contrasts between plantation economies and small units; high concentration of land ownership, income, and power and dire poverty; modern farming and relatively backward cultivation methods; and nationalism and extensive foreign ownership of land. In addition, Latin-American society is complicated by its ethnic mixtures and by dependence on staple trade items such as sugar, tobacco, cocoa, coffee, and beef cattle.Reform in Latin America has reflected the ideologies and objectives of the regime in power. Brazil has had several attempts at reform. The measures have been indirect and relatively mild, the most important being taxation of idle land and large plantations and reclamation and settlement of the Amazon region, with provisions for credit and tenancy protection. The results have been modest, however, largely because of the physical and biological hardships faced by settlers in the tropical Amazon environment. Peru has deviated by creating collective administrations of the nationalized feudal estates. The title resides in the nation, and the estates are run by the Agricultural Societies of Social Interest (SAIS), a mechanism devised to avoid breaking up economically efficient enterprises rather than to modify the tenure institutions.At the other end of the Latin-American spectrum is the Cuban (Cuba) reform that followed the revolution of 1958. Cuba retained private ownership but reduced it substantially in favour of the public sector. As proclaimed a few months before the overthrow of the old regime, the reform aimed at the elimination of latifundia tenure, expropriation of land owned by foreign companies, higher standards of living for the peasantry, and national economic development. It began by setting a ceiling of 30 caballerías (one caballería = 33 acres, or 13.4 hectares) on individual holdings, with a maximum of 100 caballerías if economic operations required such a scale. All foreign-owned land was nationalized. Public land on which rice and cattle were raised was converted into state farms, and the peasants became permanent wage workers on these farms. Sugar plantations were converted into cooperatives to avoid their subdivision into small uneconomic units. Before long the ceiling on individual holdings was lowered to five caballerías, and all such holdings became private family farms. The rest were nationalized, and the expropriated owners were compensated with a pension for life. The reform was supplemented by the organization of national farmer associations; people's stores; credit, housing, and educational facilities; and the production of machinery and fertilizers. In 1963 a major reorganization of state farms took place; they were subdivided on the basis of crop specialization into smaller operational units of about 469 caballerías.Effects of the reform were comprehensive and immediate. The tenure institutions were radically changed in favour of public ownership, while minifundia and tenancies were abolished. Socially and politically, the reform realized the objectives of the reformers. Economically, the government claimed higher yields of sugarcane, vegetables, and fruit, but this claim has been disputed by foreign observers.Other Latin-American reforms fall between those of Brazil and Cuba, though closer to the former than to the latter in comprehensiveness and thoroughness. For example, the reform in Costa Rica has overlooked land concentration and income inequality and concentrated on the squatters, or parásitos, who in 1961 numbered between 12,000 and 16,000 people. The reform aimed at legalizing existing squatter holdings, preventing further squatting, and conserving virgin land. Even this modest program was implemented very slowly. As late as 1973, 7.3 percent of the landholdings comprised 67 percent of the total agricultural land. Colombia has had reform programs for at least 30 years, but concentration of ownership, fragmented holdings, backward methods of cultivation, inequality of income distribution, and widespread poverty have remained characteristic; in 1970, 4.3 percent of the holdings contained 67.4 percent of the total area.Chile undertook various reform programs before achieving concrete results. In 1962 a program was enacted to encourage settlement of new land, but only about 1,000 families were settled. A comprehensive reform was introduced in 1965 with three main objectives: to make the agricultural workers owners of the land they had cultivated previously, to increase agricultural and livestock production, and to facilitate social mobility and peasant participation in political life. The Chilean reform was unique in its method of implementation. Once the plantation had been designated for expropriation and the prospective owners selected, they were organized into asentamientos, or settlement groups. The group elected a committee to take charge of settlement. The members cultivated the land as a team for three to five years. Meanwhile they received training and guidance in social participation, decision making, and modern farming. Upon completion of the transition period, the land was divided among those who had shown promise, to be held outright and without restriction. All new owners were obligated to join cooperatives, the form of these being determined by the members. The socialist regime that came into office in 1970 expedited the expropriation process and the creation of settlement groups or cooperative farms under peasant committees. By 1972 all the potential land, which had been in farms larger than 200 acres (80 hectares), had been expropriated and reallocated. The new regime that took over in 1973 decided, however, to privatize the land and reverse much of the reform by returning large areas to the former owners, dissolving the cooperatives, and creating private ownerships in their place. Most of the reverse changes had been completed by 1979. Nevertheless, most of the excess land in farms of more than 200 acres remained in the hands of the reform beneficiaries. Owners of less than 12 acres (five hectares) were hardly affected; those who owned between 12 and 50 acres (five and 20 hectares) benefitted most. In the final analysis, less than 15 percent of the agricultural land was affected by the reform between 1965 and 1979 under three regimes.Observers of the Latin-American scene have been pessimistic regarding the adequacy of these land reform programs. With the exception of Cuba, capital formation in agriculture has not increased substantially; the pattern of land distribution has undergone little change; social and political stability have remained in question; and the agrarian structure is still considered defective.Other recent reformsAttempts to reform the agrarian structure have been made in most other countries, with varying degrees of seriousness. India and Pakistan have concentrated on abolishing intermediaries who prevailed as survivals of traditional and feudal tenures. In India the tenants have become hereditary holders, with the title vested in the state. India has left reform to the states and emphasized peaceful and compensatory methods; hence the results have varied from one state to another. Pakistan, following the revolution of 1958, enacted a reform that made most of the tenants owners. In both countries, however, small-scale farming has persisted, while Pakistan has continued to tolerate and protect owners of up to 500 acres (200 hectares). In neither country has fragmentation been effectively reduced or have capital formation and cultivation methods significantly advanced.In contrast, after the Communists came to power in China, private ownership was eliminated and the peasants were organized in village communes. Extensive supplementary measures have been tried, and the role and organization of the commune have varied according to the pressures on the economy. The most recent innovation in China's agriculture has been the “production responsibility system,” which allows the commune to contract with its members for quotas of output; the members are free to sell the surplus on the open market. The change is seen as an incentive generator, but land cannot be rented, bought, sold, or used except as authorized by the commune. The effects of China's agrarian policy on peasant living conditions and the Chinese economy have been generally accepted as positive, genuine, and impressive.In 1962 Iran made owners of most of the former sharecroppers, in the classic tradition of Western-type reform, mainly to create political stability. Given Iran's revolution of 1979, however, the reform evidently was not sufficient to sustain the old social order. Reform was also introduced in Syria, Iraq, Algeria, Libya, and other countries of the Middle East and North Africa following independence or revolution. Most of these reforms were influenced by the Egyptian example, with the state playing a major role. In all cases emphasis has been placed on farm cooperatives, although they have been largely ineffective.In contrast, tropical Africa has witnessed a wave of innovative reform in recent years. Reform has sometimes come in “packages,” which combine tenure reform and other measures affecting cultivation and productivity. Among the innovations is the “villagization,” or ujamaa, program of Tanzania, according to which a group of families lives, works, and makes decisions together and shares the costs and benefits of farming the land. The program began as a voluntary movement in 1967, but by 1977 it had become almost mandatory. At the same time, “block farming” and individual holdings had become acceptable forms of cooperation. The Ujamaa Villages Act of 1975 made the village the main rural administration and development unit. The most radical reforms in Africa, however, have been those of Ethiopia in 1975 and of Mozambique in 1979. Both vested the land title in the nation and abolished rent, sale, and absentee control of the land. The land was placed in the hands of the tillers, who have guaranteed right of use for themselves and for their descendants. Except in the public sector, farming is a small, family operation with a high degree of equality of landholding but of uncertain efficiency.ConclusionsLand reform and agrarian reforms have become synonymous, indicating that reform programs have become more comprehensive and encompass much more than the reform of land tenure or land distribution. Reform movements have recurred throughout history, as have the crises they are intended to deal with, because reform has rarely dealt with the roots of the crises. Reform has served as a problem-solving mechanism and therefore has only been extensive enough to cope with the immediate crisis. Reformers have often faced hard choices: to promote and sustain private ownership with inequality or to institute public or collective ownership with equality but with restrictions on the individuals' private interests; to spread employment by supporting labour-intensive, low-productivity techniques or to promote high productivity through capital-intensive, efficient methods; to pursue gradual “repair and maintenance” reform that is basically ineffective or to promote revolutionary, comprehensive, effective but disruptive reform. In capitalist reforms these contradictions have usually been resolved in favour of the first set of options; in socialist reforms, in favour of the second. Land tenure reform seems to have been of little significance in creating substantive economic change, although it has been important for improving the status of peasants and maintaining social and political stability. Most reforms have narrowed the gap between reform beneficiaries and other farmers through land redistribution and tenancy control, but only the comprehensive socialist reforms have narrowed the gap between agriculture and other sectors of the economy.Land redistribution programs have had limited success for several reasons. They often have deprived the farm of the former landlord's contributions without providing a substitute. They have inhibited mobility of labour by giving the peasant a stake in the land, though only in the form of an inefficient minifarm. They frequently have threatened large, efficiently run farms and therefore have had to be compromised. They have provided compensation for the expropriated land and hence left wealth and income distribution largely unaffected. They have been conditional upon peasant participation in social and political activity and cooperative organization, even though the peasant was unprepared for these activities. Moreover, the redistribution of land has rarely been fortified by protective measures that could prevent reconcentration of ownership and the recurrence of crises. Nevertheless, major efforts have been expended by the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations and other international bodies and by governments to devise viable frameworks for solving agricultural and rural problems emanating from defective agrarian structures.Additional ReadingThe philosophy and logic of land reform are presented in A. Whitney Griswold, Farming and Democracy (1948, reissued 1963), a lucid scholarly analysis of the political significance of various farm structures and a discussion of the family farm as a cornerstone of democracy; Folke Dovring, Land and Labor in Europe in the Twentieth Century, 3rd rev. ed. (1965), an examination of the political and ideological bases of land policy since the French Revolution; Elias H. Tuma, Twenty-Six Centuries of Agrarian Reform: A Comparative Analysis (1965), a synthesis of theory and history, with an attempt to formulate a general theory of agrarian reform, and “Agrarian Reform in Historical Perspective Revisited,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 21:3–29 (1979), which updates and retests the author's earlier theory; Erich H. Jacoby, Evaluation of Agrarian Structures and Agrarian Reform Programs (1966), a checklist of administrative and organizational changes that contribute to reform success; and Doreen Warriner, Land Reform in Principle and Practice (1969), a provocative discussion of the evolution of reform and conflict between theory and practice.More recent works discussing the same issues include World Conference on Agrarian Reform and Rural Development, The Peasants' Charter (1981), a declaration of principles and program of action by most of the nonsocialist developing countries; John D. Montgomery (ed.), International Dimensions of Land Reform (1984), an overview of how such issues are handled by international agencies; Ingrid Palmer, The Impact of Agrarian Reform on Women (1985), an examination of fertility, health, and nutrition; John P. Powelson, The Story of Land: A World History of Land Tenure and Agrarian Reform (1988), a good starting place for study, with a comprehensive bibliography; Demetrios Christodoulou, The Unpromised Land: Agrarian Reform and Conflict Worldwide (1990), an excellent resource list and a fine study of the circumstances which render land reform necessary; M. Riad El-Ghonemy, The Political Economy of Rural Poverty: The Case for Land Reform (1990), a convincing argument for reduced land concentration; and Solon L. Barraclough, An End to Hunger?: The Social Origins of Food Strategies (1991), a study placing land reform issues for developing countries in the broader world context.Reforms in the ancient world are addressed in W. Warde-Fowler, “Notes on Gaius Gracchus,” English Historical Review, 20:209–227 and 417–433 (1905); E.G. Hardy, “Were the Lex Thoria of 118 BC. and the Lex Agraria of 111 BC Reactionary Laws?,” Journal of Philosophy, 31:268–286 (1910); Ivan M. Linforth, Solon the Athenian (1919, reprinted 1971); and W.J. Woodhouse, Solon the Liberator: A Study of the Agrarian Problems in Attica in the Seventh Century (1938, reprinted 1965).Elias H. Tuma, European Economic History: Tenth Century to the Present (1971), summarizes the agrarian reform history of most countries of Europe since the Middle Ages. Early French reforms are examined by Marc Bloch, French Rural History: An Essay on Its Basic Characteristics (1966; originally published in French, 1931); and Georges Lefebvre, The Coming of the French Revolution: 1789, bicentennial ed. (1989; originally published in French, 1939). Reform in tsarist Russia is addressed in Geroid T. Robinson, Rural Russia Under the Old Régime: A History of the Landlord-Peasant World and a Prologue to the Peasant Revolution of 1917 (1932, reissued 1969).Any study of recent decades must begin with Progress in Land Reform: Sixth Report (1976), issued jointly by the United Nations, its Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), and the International Labour Organisation; and with two publications from the FAO, Review and Analysis of Agrarian Reform and Rural Development in the Developing Countries Since the Mid-1960s (1979?), and Land Reform, Land Settlement, and Cooperatives (semiannual), which offers feature articles, summaries of recent reform legislation, and a comprehensive bibliography of new literature.Summaries and analyses of reform over broad regions can be found in Jean Le Coz, Les Réformes agraires: de Zapata à Mao Tsé-toung et la F.A.O. (1974), which compares the Soviet model with the Chinese, and with reform in Latin America and the Middle East, and highlights the role of the FAO in reform implementation; V.E. Stanis, Socialist Transformation of Agriculture: Theory and Practice (1976; originally published in Russian, 1971), covering reform in eastern Europe after World War II; Russell King, Land Reform: A World Survey (1977), a good summary for the general reader, with references; David A. Preston (ed.), Environment, Society, and Rural Change in Latin America: The Past, Present, and Future in the Countryside (1980), a collection of essays, pessimistic as to the efficacy of most reform; Ajit Kumar Ghose (ed.), Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries (1983), covering developments in agrarian reform through the early 1980s, with illustrations from the field; M. Riad El-Ghonemy (ed.), How Development Strategies Benefit the Rural Poor (1984), an FAO summary of reform programs; and Peter Utting, Economic Reform and Third-World Socialism: A Political Economy of Food Policy in Transitional Societies (1992), a lucid introduction to certain economic aspects of land reform in socialist economies.Studies of specific countries and regions which also highlight important theoretical trends include Maurice H. Dobb, Soviet Economic Development Since 1917, 6th ed. (1966); George Yaney, The Urge to Mobilize: Agrarian Reform in Russia, 1861–1930 (1982); John Yin, Infrastructure of the Soviet Agriculture (1991); Eric J. Hooglund, Land and Revolution in Iran, 1960–1980 (1982); Elias H. Tuma, Economic and Political Change in the Middle East (1987); Asghar Schirazi, Islamic Development Policy: The Agrarian Question in Iran (1993); Kenneth M. Luno, The Pasha's Peasants: Land, Society, and Economy in Lower Egypt, 1740–1858 (1992), providing historical perspective; James Brow and Joe Weeramunda (eds.), Agrarian Change in Sri Lanka (1992); James Putzel, A Captive Land: The Politics of Agrarian Reform in the Philippines (1992), a detailed and erudite study; John O. Haley and Kozo Yamamura (eds.), Land Issues in Japan: A Policy Failure? (1992); William Hinton, The Great Reversal: The Privatization of China, 1978–1989 (1990), discussing the mixture of collective and private approaches to land-use practices; Vivienne Shue, Peasant China in Transition: The Dynamics of Development Toward Socialism, 1949–1956 (1980), a close study of the initial stages of agricultural development and state control of the rural economy; Anthony Y.C. Koo, Land Market Distortion and Tenure Reform (1982), concentrating on Taiwan and Southeast Asia; Laura J. Enríquez, Harvesting Change: Labor and Agrarian Reform in Nicaragua, 1979–1990 (1991), an unusual and particularly valuable work because of its revolutionary setting; Steven E. Sanderson, Agrarian Populism and the Mexican State: The Struggle for Land in Sonora (1981), covering 1917–76, with much discussion of the national situation; and Roger Bartra, Agrarian Structure and Political Power in Mexico (1993), illuminating the debate over small-scale agriculture versus other, more corporate forms.Some excellent sources on African land-reform issues and policies which have not been widely available until recently are Essy M. Letsoalo, Land Reform in South Africa: A Black Perspective (1987), an essential majority perspective; Fred T. Hendricks, The Pillars of Apartheid: Land Tenure, Rural Planning, and the Chieftaincy (1990), which covers some of the homeland issues; Michael De Klerk (ed.), A Harvest of Discontent: The Land Question in South Africa (1991), which details the controversial South African situation; and Thomas J. Bassett and Donald E. Crummey (eds.), Land in African Agrarian Systems (1993), a collection of essays covering much of the continent.Elias H. Tuma* * *
Universalium. 2010.